image missing
HOME SN-BRIEFS SYSTEM
OVERVIEW
EFFECTIVE
MANAGEMENT
PROGRESS
PERFORMANCE
PROBLEMS
POSSIBILITIES
STATE
CAPITALS
FLOW
ACTIVITIES
FLOW
ACTORS
PETER
BURGESS
SiteNav SitNav (0) SitNav (1) SitNav (2) SitNav (3) SitNav (4) SitNav (5) SitNav (6) SitNav (7) SitNav (8)
Date: 2025-03-22 Page is: DBtxt001.php txt00023462
ECONOMICS
CRITIQUE OF NOBEL PRIZE CHOICES

Bernanke v. Kindleberger: Which Credit Channel?



Original article: https://www.ineteconomics.org/perspectives/blog/bernanke-v-kindleberger-which-credit-channel
Peter Burgess COMMENTARY
This is a delightful piece ... right up my memory lane.

The following is an extract from the comments associated with this article:
G.Visakh Varma • 6 days ago
Only mainstream economists mostly American economists who exhibits mathematical gymnastics are chosen by the Nobel committee. It is customary that out of 3 Nobel economists, one must be a Chicagoan. Great economists like Professor Joan Robinson and Professor Nicky Kaldor were not awarded the prize. Even versatile economists like Professor William Baumol or Professor Martin Weitzman were not selected. If Lord Keynes was alive the Nobel committee would not have awarded him Nobel prize

My reply:
I could not agree more with this comment. I was a student of economics at Cambridge in the late 1950s when Joan Robinson and Nicholas Kaldor were prominent around the department and Keynes very much foundational to everything I was expected to learn. Some 60 years later, I still find their economic thinking made more sense than much of the mindless econometrics that has become more and more fashionable and perhaps explains the power of 'financialization' that has been doing untold damage to society as well as the environment. Keynes would be appalled !!!!!!!!!!!!!!
Perry Mehrling has reminded me of my days as an economics student at Cambridge where the shadow of Keynes was everywhere and some important Keynes acolytes from the 1930s like Joan Robinson and Nicholas Kaldor and others were carrying the torch.

One of my takeaways from my time at Cambridge was that Keynes was constantly striving better to understand what was actually going on with society and the economy ... and wanted policy to be the best it could possibly be given what we knew (or did not know) about its behavior.

I am afraid I had not realized until today that some of the work that Nicholas Kaldor was doing while he was at Cambridge has something in common with what I am trying to do 60+ years later. When I looked at Kaldor's Wikipedia page I was taken by the image shown at the end of this webpage. Specifically, the idea that there are multiple drivers of economic change, not one single driver. This should be pretty obvious ... and I was very much aware of it when I was working on engineering and technical problems, but when it came to economics, one of the biggest and complex 'systems' that there is, the assumption are usually unbelievable simplistics and it is no wonder that the results are rarely of much 'real world' value.

The more I look at the writing of people who claim to know something about economics, banking and finance, I am surprised at how little I tend to agree with. The people with actual experience are usually writing about the little bubble where they work without knowing much about the massive amount of economic activity going on outside their bubble, and the people who write about the big picture have usually not much experience of how all the real-world decisions are getting made all the time in real-time.
Peter Burgess
Bernanke v. Kindleberger: Which Credit Channel?

By Perry G. Mehrling

OCT 13, 2022 | MACROECONOMICS

In the papers of economist Charles Kindleberger, Perry Mehrling found notes on the paper that won Ben Bernanke his Nobel Prize.

In the 1983 paper cited as the basis for Bernanke’s Nobel award, the first footnote states: “I have received useful comments from too many people to list here by name, but I am grateful to each of them.” One of those unnamed commenters was Charles P. Kindleberger, who taught at MIT full-time until mandatory retirement in 1976 and then half-time for another five years. Bernanke himself earned his MIT Ph.D. in 1979, whereupon he shifted to Stanford as Assistant Professor. Thus it was natural for him to send his paper to Kindleberger for comment, and perhaps also natural for Kindleberger to respond.

As it happens, the carbon copy of that letter has been preserved in the Kindleberger Papers at MIT, and that copy is reproduced below as possibly of contemporary interest. All footnotes are mine, referencing the specific passages of the published paper, a draft copy of which Kindleberger is apparently addressing, and filling in context that would have been familiar to both Bernanke and Kindleberger but may not be to a modern reader. With these explanatory notes, the text speaks for itself and requires no further commentary from me.
---------------------------
“May 1, 1982 Dr. Ben Bernanke Graduate School of Business, Stanford University. Stanford, CA 94305 Dear Dr. Bernanke, Thank you for sending me your paper on the great depression. You ask for comments, and I assume this is not merely ceremonial. I am afraid you will not in fact welcome them. I think you have provided a most ingenious solution to a non-problem.[1] The necessity to demonstrate that financial crisis can be deleterious to production arises only in the scholastic precincts of the Chicago school with what Reder called in the last JEL its tight priors, or TP.[2] If one believes in rational expectations, a natural rate of unemployment, efficient markets, exchange rates continuously at purchasing power parities, there is not much that can be explained about business cycles or financial crises. For a Chicagoan, you are courageous to depart from the assumption of complete markets.[3] You wave away Minsky and me for departing from rational assumptions.[4] Would you not accept that it is possible for each participant in a market to be rational but for the market as a whole to be irrational because of the fallacy of composition? If not, how can you explain chain letters, betting on lotteries, panics in burning theatres, stock market and commodity bubbles as the Hunts in silver, the world in gold, etc… Assume that the bootblack, waiters, office boys etc of 1929 were rational and Paul Warburg who said the market was too high in February 1929 was not entitled to such an opinion. Each person hoping to get in an[d] out in time may be rational, but not all can accomplish it. Your data are most interesting and useful. It was not Temin who pointed to the spread (your DIF) between governts [sic] and Baa bond yields, but Friedman and Schwartz.[5] Column 4 also interests me for its behavior in 1929. It would be interesting to disaggregate between loans on securities on the one hand and loans and discounts on the other. Your rejection of money illusion (on the ground of rationality) throws out any role for price changes. I think this is a mistake on account at least of lags and dynamics. No one of the Chicago stripe pays attention to the sharp drop in commodity prices in the last quarter of 1929, caused by the banks, in their concern over loans on securities, to finance commodities sold in New York on consignment (and auto loans).[6] This put the pressure on banks in areas with loans on commodities. The gainers from the price declines were slow in realizing their increases. The banks of the losers failed. Those of the ultimate winners did not expand. Note, too, the increase in failures, the decrease in credit and the rise in DIF in the last four of five months of 1931.[7] Much of this, after September 21, was the consequence of the appreciation of the dollar from $4.86 to $3.25.[8] Your international section takes no account of this because prices don’t count in your analysis. In The World in Depression, 1929-1939, which you do not list,[9] I make much of this structural deflation, the mirror analogue of structural inflation today from core inflation and the oil shock. But your priors do not permit you to think them of any importance.

Sincerely yours,

[Charles P. Kindleberger]”

References
  • Bernanke, Ben S. 1983. “Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression.” American Economic Review 73 No 3 (June): 257-276.
  • Kindleberger, Charles P. 1973. The World in Depression, 1929-1939. Berkeley CA: University of California Press.
  • Kindleberger, Charles P. 1978. Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises. New York: Basic Books.
  • Kindleberger, Charles P. 1985. Keynesianism vs. Monetarism and Other Essays in Financial History. London: George Allen and Unwin.
  • Kindleberger. Charles P. and Jean-Pierre Laffargue, eds. 1982. Financial crises: Theory, History, and Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Mehrling, Perry. 2022. Money and Empire: Charles P. Kindleberger and the Dollar System. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Notes
  1. [1] Bernanke (1983, 258): “reconciliation of the obvious inefficiency of the depression with the postulate of rational private behavior”.
  2. [2] Reder, Melvin W. “Chicago Economics: Permanence and Change.” Journal of Economic Literature 20 No. 1 (March 1982): 1-38. Bernanke (1983, 257) states explicitly, “the present paper builds on the Friedman-Schwartz work…”
  3. [3] Bernanke (1983, 257): “The basic premise is that, because markets for financial claims are incomplete, intermediation between some classes of borrowers and lenders requires nontrivial market-making and information-gathering services.” And again at p. 263: “We shall clearly not be interested in economies of the sort described by Eugene Fama (1980), in which financial markets are complete and information/transactions costs can be neglected.”
  4. [4] Bernanke (1983, 258): “Hyman Minsky (1977) and Charles Kindleberger (1978) have in several places argued for the inherent instability of the financial system, but in doing so have had to depart from the assumption of rational economic behavior.” It is perhaps relevant to observe that elsewhere Kindleberger takes pains to point out the limitations of the Minsky model for explaining the great depression: “it is limited to the United States; there are no capital movements, no exchange rates, no international commodity prices, nor even any impact of price changes on bank liquidity for domestic commodities; all assets are financial.” (Kindleberger 1985, 302) This passage appears in Kindleberger’s contribution to a 1981 conference sponsored by the Banca di Roma and MIT’s Sloan School of Management, which followed on a 1979 Bad Homburg conference that also included both men, which proceedings were published as Financial Crises: Theory, History and Policy (Cambridge 1982).
  5. [5] Bernanke (1983, 262): “DIF = difference (in percentage points) between yields on Baa corporate bonds and long-term U.S. government bonds”.
  6. [6] It is exactly the sharp drop in commodity prices that Kindleberger puts at the center of his explanation of why the depression was worldwide since commodity prices are world prices. Kindleberger (1973, 104): “The view taken here is that symmetry may obtain in the scholar’s study, but that it is hard to find in the real world. The reason is partly money illusion, which hides the fact of the gain in purchasing power from the consumer countries facing lower prices; and partly the dynamics of deflation, which produce an immediate response in the country of falling prices, and a slow one, often overtaken by spreading deflation, in the country with improved terms of trade, i.e. lower import prices.”
  7. [7] Bernanke’s Table 1 cites August-December DIF figures as follows: 4.29, 4.82, 5.41, 5.30, 6.49.
  8. [8] September 21 is of course the date when the Bank of England took sterling off gold, see Kindleberger (1973, 167-170).
  9. [9] The published version, Bernanke (1983), still does not list Kindleberger (1973), citing only Kindleberger (1978), Manias, Panics, and Crashes. Notably, the full title of that book includes also the words “A History of Financial Crises.” Kindleberger himself quite explicitly frames Manias as an extension of the Depression book, now including all of the international financial crises he can find. Later commentary however follows Bernanke in viewing Kindleberger (1978) as instead an extension of Minsky’s essentially domestic Financial Instability Hypothesis, which is not correct. On this point see footnote 4, and more generally, Chapter 8 of my book Money and Empire (Cambridge 2022).
Perry G. Mehrling
Academic Council
Professor of Economics, Boston University


Shifting, multiple equilibria lead to six-stage business cycle in which the economy oscillates around optimal income growth and generates phases of boom and bust.


See Wikipedia: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Nicholas_Kaldor



The text being discussed is available at
https://www.ineteconomics.org/perspectives/blog/bernanke-v-kindleberger-which-credit-channel
and
SITE COUNT<
Amazing and shiny stats
Blog Counters Reset to zero January 20, 2015
TrueValueMetrics (TVM) is an Open Source / Open Knowledge initiative. It has been funded by family and friends. TVM is a 'big idea' that has the potential to be a game changer. The goal is for it to remain an open access initiative.
WE WANT TO MAINTAIN AN OPEN KNOWLEDGE MODEL
A MODEST DONATION WILL HELP MAKE THAT HAPPEN
The information on this website may only be used for socio-enviro-economic performance analysis, education and limited low profit purposes
Copyright © 2005-2021 Peter Burgess. All rights reserved.