image missing
Date: 2025-02-13 Page is: DBtxt003.php txt00009322

Issues
The Nature of the Corporation

Statement on Economics

Burgess COMMENTARY

Peter Burgess

Statement on Economics

1. The changing economic conceptualisation of the corporation.

From the early decades of the twentieth century, a dominant characteristic of the modern “capitalist” corporation, especially in the United States, was the separation of asset ownership in the form of publicly traded shares from allocative control over the corporation’s resources by salaried managers (Berle and Means 1932). By the 1950s some depicted managerial-controlled large enterprise as the “soulful” corporation in which the allocation of resources resulted in enhanced social welfare (Kaysen 1957; Mason 1959). In the 1960s, however, some conservative academics looked to market forces, dubbed the ‘market for corporate control’, to ensure that managers as employees would give primacy to shareholders in the allocation of corporate resources (Manne 1962). This market for corporate control could enable hostile takeovers in which shareholders who accumulated large public equity stakes in a company could discipline managers to allocate resources in ways that “the market” deemed to be efficient. The notion that market allocation could control managerial organization was then developed theoretically based on the conceptualisation that the corporation (and indeed any firm) could be conceptualised as a ‘nexus of contracts’ or a ‘collection of assets’ (Cheung 1983; Grossman and Hart 1986; Jensen and Meckling 1976). Rather than view the corporation as a social organization with its unique history and competitive capabilities in which public shareholders had come to play a peripheral role (Chandler 1962 and 1977), neoclassical economists conceptualised the corporation as a set of voluntary contracts among owners of resources and as a portfolio of assets with different market-determined rates of returns (Bratton 1989; Ireland 1999).

2. Maximising Shareholder Value (MSV) as the sole objective of corporate governance.

This conceptualisation of the corporation to fit with the dominant neoclassical theory of the market economy had two core implications. First, it made market-based financial metrics central to corporate strategy and to relations within the corporation (Daily et al. 2003; Davis 2009; Ireland 2009; Lazonick 1992). Second, shareholders could be portrayed as the only risk-bearers since they were the only participants in the corporation who did not get a guaranteed market-determined return for their productive contributions (Blair, 1995). On the assumption that risk results in superior overall economic performance, the central problem became how to align the interests of managers as agents with those of shareholders as principals. The ‘stick’ was the hostile takeover exercised through the market for corporate control (Jensen 1986). But these economists also argued that the ‘carrot’ of stock-based pay could induce executives to allocate corporate resources to maximize shareholder value (Jensen and Murphy 1990). By the 1990s the triumph of MSV as an ideology of corporate governance was virtually complete, with senior executive pay tied to stock-price performance, legitimized by MSV ideology (Davis 2009; Lazonick and O’Sullivan 2000).

3. Short-termism prevails and investments in productive capability diminish.

A view of corporate governance focused on immediate market metrics and MSV reduces the overall time horizon of strategic decision making (Hellman 2005; Useem 1999; Stout 2012), encourages an increased emphasis on cost management and financial engineering (Krippner 2005; Froud et al. 2002), and invites increasing asset churn (mergers, acquisitions, buyouts and demergers) (Davis, 2009). MSV legitimates the replacement of a ‘retain and reinvest’ allocation regime that invests in productive capabilities with a ‘downsize and distribute’ regime that downsizes the labour force and distributes the resultant ‘free’ cash flow to shareholders (Lazonick and O’Sullivan 2000). MSV thus diverts the use of corporate cash flows away from productive investment and supports a decline in innovativeness (Dobbin and Jung 2010).

4. Redistribution of income to public shareholders and corporate executives.

In the United States, under MSV, for the 251 companies in the S&P 500 Index in January 2013 that were publicly listed back to 1981, the buyback payout ratio – that is, repurchases as a proportion of net income – was less than 5% in 1981-1983 but 39% in 2010-2012, with a three-year peak of 70% in 2006-2008. From the 1980s to the 1990s to the 2000s, the dividend payout ratio declined from 50% to 44% to 41%, while the buyback payout ratio rose from 22% to 35% to 50% (Lazonick 2014b). The top executives who made those allocation decisions were the prime beneficiaries through their stock options and stock awards; in 2012 the remuneration of the 500 highest paid executives averaged $30.3 million of which 82% came from stock-based pay.

5. Increased within-country income inequalities…

Soaring executive pay has been the main driver of concentration of income among the top 0.1% of households in the United States (Piketty 2014). Beyond the direct redistribution of income in favour of shareholders and corporate executives, a wider macroeconomic consequence of the way in which company profits are divided is a steep increase in income inequalities between labour and capital within economies. From the early 1980s, productivity growth has been outstripping real wage growth, leading to a strongly declining factor share of labour in national income in almost all Western countries over the past thirty years (Davis, 2009; Dobbin and Zorn 2005; Froud et al. 2002; Froud and Williams 2007; Ireland 2005; Ireland 2009; Lazonick and O’Sullivan 2000; Lazonick 2014b; Stout 2012).

6. …through a race to the bottom in employment conditions and taxation powers.

This trend towards growing structural income inequalities is closely related to shareholder primacy. MSV leads to a decline in stable, well-paid employment opportunities (Widmer 2011; Thompson 2013). Of particular importance has been the end of the employment norm of a career with one company that prevailed at most corporations throughout the 1980s (Lazonick 2013). In addition, corporate governance models based on MSV legitimize the use of international tax structures through tax havens as a strategic imperative, shaping global value chains (Froud et al 2002; Milberg 2008). This pursuit of MSV erodes the tax bases of the jurisdictions that provide for high-quality physical and technological infrastructure, education, health and welfare and educated workers that corporations rely on for their continued operations (Ireland 2005 and 2009; Martin 2010; Stout 2012; OECD 2013). The strategic imperatives of MSV at the firm level thus impact directly on the political and economic framework in which firms, states and trade blocs operate.

7. Marginalisation of investments by other stakeholders in the economy.

MSV runs on the assumption that shareholders are the only participants in the economy who bear risk, that is, they are the only investors without a guaranteed return (Blair 1995). However, taxpayers, workers and governments make risky investments in productive capabilities on a regular basis to create value-creating capabilities that enable the business enterprise to generate competitive products. These stakeholders, therefore, hold a legitimate economic claim to profits, if and when they occur. But MSV ignores these risky investments by stakeholders, while according primacy to public shareholders who typically merely buy and sell outstanding shares (Aglietta and Rebérioux 2005; Lazonick 2014a).

8. Economic instability rather than economic efficiency.

There is no doubt that MSV has triumphed as a theory of resource allocation in favour of specific interest groups. It has contributed to a concentration of income at the top. Far from promoting economic efficiency, MSV is a core factor in growing macroeconomic imbalances, instability and the erosion of innovative capability (Lapavitsas 2013; Stockhammer 2004 and 2012). It is destructive of the long-term relations with constituencies upon which corporations ultimately rely and does not even benefit the mass of public shareholders over the long run as the massive distributions to shareholders and the explosion of executive pay have undermined the innovative capability of the corporate economy (Lazonick 2013 and 2014b).

References

Aglietta, M. & Rebérioux, A. 2005, Corporate governance adrift: a critique of shareholder value, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, UK.

Berle, A.A. & Means, G.C. 2007[1932], The modern corporation and private property, Rev. edn, Transaction, New Brunswick, N.J ; London.

Blair, M. 1995, Ownership and Control: Rethinking Corporate Governance for the Twenty-first Century, Brookings, Washington, D.C..

Bratton Jr, W.W. 1989, “The New Economic Theory of the Firm: Critical Perspectives from History”, Stanford Law Review, vol. 41, no. 6, pp. 1471-1527.

Chandler, A.D. 1962, Strategy and structure: chapters in the history of the industrial enterprise, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.

Chandler, A.D. 1977, The visible hand: The managerial revolution in American business, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, USA.

Cheung, S.N. 1983, “The contractual nature of the firm”, Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 26, no. 1, pp. 1-21.

Daily, C.M., Dalton, D.R. & Cannella, A.A. 2003, “Corporate governance: decades of dialogue and data.”, Academy of Management Review, vol. 28, no. 3, pp. 371-382.

Davis, G.F. 2009, Managed by the Markets: How Finance Re-Shaped America, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Dobbin, F. & Jung, J. 2010, “The misapplication of Mr. Michael Jensen: How agency theory brought down the economy and why it might again”, Research in the Sociology of Organizations, vol. 30, pp. 29-64.

Dobbin, F. & Zorn, D. 2005, “Corporate malfeasance and the myth of shareholder value”, Political power and social theory, vol. 17, pp. 179-198.

Froud, J., Johal, S. & Williams, K. 2002, “Financialisation and the coupon pool”, Capital & Class, vol. 26, no. 3, pp. 119-151.

Froud, J. & Williams, K. 2007, “Private equity and the culture of value extraction”, New Political Economy, vol. 12, no. 3, pp. 405-420.

Grossman, S.J. & Hart, O.D. 1986, “The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration”, The Journal of Political Economy, vol. 94, no. 2, pp. 691-719.

Hellman, N. 2005, “Can we expect institutional investors to improve corporate governance?”, Scandinavian Journal of Management, vol. 21, no. 3, pp. 293-327.

Ireland, P. 2009, “Financialization and corporate governance”, Northern Ireland Legal Quarterly, vol. 60, no. 1, pp. 1-34.

Ireland, P. 2005, “Shareholder Primacy and the Distribution of Wealth”, The Modern Law Review, vol. 68, no. 1, pp. 49-81.

Ireland, P. 1999, “Company Law and the Myth of Shareholder Ownership”, The Modern Law Review, vol. 62, no. 1, pp. 32-57.

Jensen, M.C. & Meckling, W.H. 1976, “Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure”, Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 3, no. 4, pp. 305-360.

Jensen, M.C. 1986, “Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers”, The American Economic Review, vol. 76, no. 2, pp. 323-329.

Jensen, M.C. & Murphy, K.J. 1990, “Performance pay and top-management incentives”, Journal of political economy, vol. 98, no. 2, pp. 225-264.

Kaysen, C. 1957, “The Social Significance of the Modern Corporation”, The American Economic Review, vol. 47, no. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Sixty-eighth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, pp. pp. 311-319.

Krippner, G.R. 2005, “The financialization of the American economy”, Socio-Economic Review, vol. 3, no. 2, pp. 173-208.

Lazonick, W. & O’Sullivan, M. 2000, “Maximizing shareholder value: a new ideology for corporate governance”, Economy and Society, vol. 29, no. 1, pp. 13-35.

Lazonick, W. 2014a, “Innovative enterprise and shareholder value”, Law and Financial Markets Review, vol. 8, no. 1, pp. 52-64.

Lazonick, W. 2014b, “Profits Without Prosperity: Stock Buybacks Manipulate the Market and Leave Most Americans Worse Off”, Harvard Business Review, September: pp. 47-55.

Lazonick, W. 2013, “The Financialization of the US Corporation: What has been Lost, and How it can be Regained”, Seattle University Law Review, vol. 36, pp. 857-910.

Lazonick, W. 1992, “Controlling the market for corporate control: the historical significance of managerial capitalism”, Industrial and Corporate Change, vol. 1, no. 3, pp. 445-488.

Manne, H.G. 1962, “The” Higher Criticism” of the Modern Corporation”, Columbia law review, vol. 62, pp. 399-432.

Martin, R. 2010, “The age of customer capitalism”, Harvard business review, vol. 88, no. 1, pp. 58-65.

Mason, E.S. (ed) 1959, The Corporation in Modern Society, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

Milberg, W. 2008, “Shifting sources and uses of profits: Sustaining US financialization with global value chains”, Economy and Society, vol. 37, no. 3, pp. 420-451.

OECD 2013, Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.

Piketty, T. 2014, Capital in the Twenty-first Century, Harvard University Press, Harvard.

Stockhammer, E. 2004, “Financialisation and the slowdown of accumulation”, Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 28, no. 5, pp. 719-741.

Stockhammer, E. 2012, “Financialization, income distribution and the crisis”, Investigación Económica, vol. 71, no. 279, pp. 39-70.

Stout, L.A. 2012, The shareholder value myth: How putting shareholders first harms investors, corporations, and the public, Berrett-Koehler Publishers, San Francisco.

Thompson, P. 2013, “Financialization and the workplace: extending and applying the disconnected capitalism thesis”, Work, Employment & Society, vol. 27, no. 3, pp. 472-488.

Useem, M. 1999, Investor capitalism: How money managers are changing the face of corporate America, Basic Books, New York.

Widmer, F. 2011, “Institutional investors, corporate elites and the building of a market for corporate control”, Socio-Economic Review, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 671-697.


Signatories

William Lazonick, Professor, University of Massachusetts Stephanie Blankenburg, Senior Lecturer in Economics, SOAS Julie Froud, Professor of Financial Innovation, University of Manchester Mary O’Sullivan, Professor of Economics, University of Geneva Catherine Sauviat, Senior Researcher, Institut de Recherches Economiques et Sociales Antoine Rebérioux, Professor of Economics, University of French West Indies, Research fellow at the CREDDI / LEAD and at EconomiX (U. Paris West) Ha-Joon Chang, Reader in the Political Economy of Development, University of Cambridge Mariana Mazzucato, RM Phillips Professor in the Economics of Innovation, SPRU, University of Sussex Grahame Thompson,Visiting Professor, Copenhagen Business School and Emeritus Professor, Political Economy, Open University Professor Steve Keen, Head of Economics, Politics & History, Kingston University Paolo Quattrone, Professor of Accounting, Governance and Social Innovation, University of Edinburgh Christopher May, Professor of Political Economy, Lancaster University Neil Lancastle, Senior Lecturer, De Montfort University Barbara Czarniawska, Professor, University of Gothenburg. Sweden David Knights, Professor, Lancaster University Laura Horn, Associate Professor, Roskilde University Keith Reader, Professor emeritus, University of London Institute in Paris/Glasgow Ilan Talmud, Associate Professor, University of Haifa Oleg Komlik, Lecturer, Ben-Gurion University Henning Schwardt, Post-Doctoral Fellow, University of Bremen, Germany Keith Robson, Professor, HEC Paris Luiz Alfredo Francisco Santos, PhD Candidate Universidad Complutense/IUIOG Tony Hines, Professor, Faculty of Business & Law, Manchester Metropolitan University Will Attwood-Charles, PhD Candidate, Boston College Robert E. Wright, Nef Family Chair of Political Economy, Augustana College SD Muir Houston, Lecturer, University of Glasgow Mehmet Ali Dikerdem, Associate Professor, Middlesex University Timo Walter, PhD Candidate, Institut de Hautes Etudes Internationales et du Développement, Genève Renira C. Angeles, PhD student, Doctoral School of Political Science, Public Policy and International Relations, Central European University, Budapest Maureen Boland, Sessional Lecturer, Curtin University Marie-Laure Djelic, Professor, ESSEC Business School Brendan K.O’Rourke, Research Fellow, College of Business, Dublin Institute of Technology, Ireland Nitasha Kaul, Visiting Fellow, University of Westminster John Holmwood, Professor of Sociology, Visiting Member, Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton and Campaign for the Public University Timothy Kuhn, Associate Professor, University of Colorado Boulder Patrick Ainley, Professor of Training and Education, University of Greenwich Dawa Sherpa, Research Scholar, Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi, India Philip Welch, Professor of Mathematics, University of Bristol Jan Culik, Senior Lecturer, University of Glasgow Kevin McSorley, Senior Lecturer in Sociology, University of Portsmouth Nadia Edmond Principal Lecturer, University of Brighton Steve Fleetwood, Professor, University of the West of England Andrew M. Fischer, Associate Professor, Institute of Social Studies, The Hague Guillaume Delalieux, Associate Professor in Management , Sciences Po, Lille Helena Desivilya Syna, Associate Professor, The Max Stern Yezreel Valley College Dennis Leech, Emeritus Professor of Economics, University of Warwick Michael Loughlin, Professor of Applied Philosophy, MMU Cheshire Mark Addis, Professor of Philosophy, Birmingham City University Willy Maley, Professor, University of Glasgow David Wield, Professor of Innovation and Development, Open University Roger Brown, Emeritus Professor of Higher Education Policy, Liverpool Hope University Machiko Nissanke, Professor of Economics, SOAS, University of London Stuart Farquhar, Senior Lecturer in Finance & Economics, University of Wolverhampton David J. Cooper, Professor of Accounting, University of Alberta Chris Carter, Professor of Strategy and Organization, University of Edinburgh Meera Sabaratnam, Lecturer in International Relations, SOAS Maria Aluchna, Professor, Warsaw School of Economics Roger Gill, Visiting Professor, Durham University Business School Alice Bryer, Assistant Professor of Accounting, IE Business School Peter Beusch, Assistant Professor, Gothenburg University Nabil Harfoush, Assistant Professor, OCAD University, Toronto Hein Vrolijk, Lecturer, University of Groningen Jesper Wittorff, MSc, Copenhagen Business School Bill Cooke Professor of Strategic Management, University of York Michael Pirson, Associate Professor, Fordham University David Jacobs, Associate Professor of Labor and Sustainability, Morgan State University, Baltimore, USA Alessia Contu, Professor of Management, University of Massachusetts Nihel Chabrak, Associate Professor, UAEU Paddy Ireland, Professor of Law, University of Bristol Vincenzo Bavoso, Lecturer in Commercial Law, The University of Manchester Lorenzo Massa, Assistant Professor (WU), Scientist (EPFL) Michael Smith, Head of Business Programmes, Initiatives of Change UK Nikhil Prasad Ojha, Partner, Bain & Company John McCreery, Partner, The Word Works, Ltd. Marcello Palazzi, Co-founder, B Lab Europe Allen L. White, Vice President, Tellus Institute Roger L. Martin, Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto


If you agree to this statement, please fill out the form below. Your name, title, and institutional affiliation(required) Email(required) I agree to the text in this memo(required) I agree to my name being added to the document for further dissemination(required)

SITE COUNT Amazing and shiny stats
Copyright © 2005-2021 Peter Burgess. All rights reserved. This material may only be used for limited low profit purposes: e.g. socio-enviro-economic performance analysis, education and training.